Background
Ben Thompson is the author of Stratechery, a business strategy newsletter. We cover his concept of aggregation theory, the evolution of the internet era, and how other tech trends have changed the business world for good.
Date
February 6, 2020
Episode Number
176
Tags
Venture Capital
Principles & Lessons:
- Tech's dominance is not endlessly cyclical disruption — it's the logical conclusion of structural progress. Ben challenges the prevailing Silicon Valley belief that tech will always be disrupted by the next wave. He argues instead that we've reached the natural endpoint of a long continuum: “you’ve had the compute and data storage layer expanding from one room to being omnipresent in the Cloud… you’ve had the interaction layer expanding from being batch processing… to in your pocket everywhere.” The smartphone (and iOS/Android) and cloud computing (AWS/Azure) now represent general-purpose computing’s local maxima — future changes (e.g., AR/VR, smartwatches) will be more specialized and less disruptive to the current incumbents. This view reframes disruption not as perpetual chaos but as a process that culminates in consolidation and maturity — which aligns with how most industries eventually stabilize. “That’s the heretical part — to say, ‘well, maybe you’re not so special after all.’”
- Aggregation theory reveals how control of demand in a world of abundance eclipses control of supply. Ben’s framework of aggregators (defined by direct user relationship, zero marginal costs, and declining customer acquisition costs) shows how companies like Google and Facebook win by taming the internet’s overwhelming abundance. As Ben says: “the SEO industry is in many respects an industry where people pay money to be better Google suppliers.” That reverses traditional power dynamics — aggregators don’t need suppliers; suppliers need them. Critically, value flows toward the companies that simplify choice, not toward those who own or create content. This has consequences for competition and regulation: if demand is the scarce resource, that’s where power — and rent — accumulates.
- Aggregation and platforms are distinct strategic models with different incentives and regulatory implications. Ben is explicit: aggregators (Google, Facebook) consolidate user demand, while platforms (like Microsoft Windows or Apple’s iOS) enable ecosystems of others. Aggregators commoditize supply; platforms tend to support and depend on differentiated suppliers. “The entire reason people use Shopify is because people don’t know it’s Shopify.” For platforms, success hinges on helping others succeed; for aggregators, success often means minimizing reliance on suppliers. Regulatory missteps often stem from conflating the two — trying to regulate Google like it’s Microsoft. That’s a category error with real-world policy consequences.
- Differentiation is structurally rewarded — but commoditization is the default in a world of zero marginal cost. In Ben’s analysis, the internet’s removal of constraints (e.g., shelf space, time slots, bandwidth) creates fierce competition. Unless you are truly differentiated, you're racing to the bottom. “Just the fact that the internet… means competition is so high, a lack of differentiation is going to kill you either on one side or the other.” This is why publishing, retail, and content creation have become barbell-shaped — aggregators win on scale; niche creators win on depth. Those in the middle (traditional publishers, undifferentiated brands) lose power and margin.
- High churn is not necessarily bad — in fact, in software-driven models, it can be a strength. Contrary to conventional wisdom, Ben argues that Shopify’s high merchant churn is not a weakness: “their platform is scalable… a million people can start a Shopify shop and 950,000 can go out of business and Shopify now has 50,000 new customers.” This reverses an assumption from physical business models (where onboarding and servicing are costly) — in zero-marginal-cost models, high-volume experimentation (with many failures) is an indicator of platform strength. This insight helps clarify how to interpret success metrics in digital-native businesses.
- Network effects have two distinct flavors — internalized (aggregators) and externalized (platforms) — and each shapes supplier power differently. Aggregators internalize network effects: Facebook and Google get stronger as more users participate, but they do so by commoditizing suppliers. In contrast, platform network effects are externalized — Windows is stronger because developers build differentiated apps. “Facebook does the same thing. A story from The New York Times is given the same prominence as a picture of my nephew.” Understanding whether a business reinforces supplier differentiation or erodes it is crucial to predicting where value accrues and what kinds of moats emerge.
- Scarcity defined legacy business models — but the internet rewrites value creation by removing constraints. Ben methodically walks through how previous moats — broadcast licenses, shelf space, ad time, distribution — were all about managing scarcity. Now, those constraints are gone: “Amazon has infinite shelf space… Netflix goes on and on and on.” The implication: value now accrues to whoever can help users navigate abundance, or who can create strong identity/differentiation in a world of endless options. Businesses that depend on artificial scarcity (e.g., traditional newspapers) are structurally disadvantaged unless they reinvent around this new reality.
- Bundling works — but only when built on infrastructure, not top-down intent. Ben is skeptical of “intentional” bundling efforts, noting they rarely work unless the infrastructure precedes them. He uses the cable industry as an example: “You ended up with a bundle, but the bundle came from the fact that you needed the cable.” The bundling of internet content (e.g., newsletters or podcasts) will only succeed if the delivery mechanism — the equivalent of “cable” — already connects creators and consumers. Hence, companies like Spotify or Substack could play this role, but only if they can create the connective infrastructure and avoid extracting too much rent from creators. Forced bundling without this infrastructure advantage is likely to fail.
Transcript
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣