Background
Michael J. Mauboussin is Head of Consilient Research at Counterpoint Global. We cover the sources of alpha, behavioral finance, and decision making.
Date
March 26, 2019
Episode Number
126
Tags
Public Equities
Principles & Lessons:
- Behavioral biases are not sufficient explanations for persistent market inefficiencies. While individual investors are demonstrably irrational (e.g., overconfident, prone to recency bias), Mauboussin emphasizes that individual biases do not automatically aggregate into irrational markets. Citing the wisdom of crowds framework, he notes that a market can remain efficient if its participants are diverse, independent, and have proper incentives and aggregation mechanisms: “You and I can both be overconfident... but we offset each other.” This invalidates the simplistic behavioral syllogism that irrational individuals imply irrational markets, and forces a more nuanced look at how collective behavior actually manifests.
- A persistent edge requires exploiting one of four sources of mispricing—but each comes with structural or practical limits. Mauboussin frames alpha with the BAIT acronym: Behavioral, Analytical, Informational, and Technical. Each is conceptually distinct yet often intertwined. Behavioral errors are emotionally difficult to bet against; analytical advantages often hinge on long time horizons; informational edge has been dramatically curtailed by regulation (e.g., Reg FD); and technical inefficiencies—forced selling or buying unrelated to fundamentals—are episodic and rare. His key point: “Day in, day out, markets are hard to beat. But occasionally, you get these opportunities from time to time.”
- Analytical edge is often a function of updating beliefs well, not modeling complexity. Among the BAIT sources, Mauboussin emphasizes that one of the most underappreciated forms of advantage is simply “being a good Bayesian”—that is, continuously and objectively updating one’s views in light of new information. Most investors fail here due to confirmation bias, treating ambiguous information as support for prior beliefs. He states, “All the jump balls are going to come your direction.” This simple failure in belief updating often outweighs more technical analytical sophistication.
- The capacity to exploit inefficiencies is often constrained by principal-agent problems and capital availability, not insight. Across multiple BAIT domains, Mauboussin repeatedly returns to a critical and often overlooked limiter: even if a mispricing is obvious (e.g., 3Com trading below its stake in Palm), the ability to act on it may be blocked by practical constraints—lack of borrow, redemptions, or institutional risk aversion. He quotes Seth Klarman’s ideal client as one “who cashes a check when we write one and writes a check when we ask for one,” underscoring that alpha opportunities often emerge precisely when most principals pull capital, not deploy it.
- The use of valuation multiples like EV/EBITDA must be grounded in economic logic, not heuristics. Mauboussin argues that “you have to earn the right to use a multiple,” criticizing casual use of metrics like EV/EBITDA without understanding their underlying economic assumptions. For instance, a high depreciation-to-EBITDA ratio indicates capital intensity, which implies different risk and return profiles. He warns that EBITDA can be misleading depending on accounting choices (e.g., DA mix), and says the warranted multiple must be understood in relation to return on capital and growth: “Multiples are not valuation. Multiples are shorthand for the valuation process.”
- Time arbitrage is real, but difficult due to institutional incentives and emotional discomfort. Mauboussin highlights “playing for a different time horizon” as one of the most structurally persistent advantages—but it demands capital that is both patient and insulated from short-term pressure. He points out that markets often misprice near-term noise while neglecting long-term signal, but capturing this spread requires (a) superior understanding of the long-term signal, (b) the ability to hold through periods of divergence, and (c) freedom from institutional redemption risk. Most managers, he implies, structurally cannot exploit this edge even if they see it.
- Effective probabilistic decision-making depends on discipline, not brilliance. A recurring theme in Mauboussin’s thinking is that consistent advantage stems not from unique brilliance, but from applying simple tools with rigor. He describes the use of Brier scores—scoring probabilistic predictions—to improve judgment calibration over time. This is less about forecasting precision than about honest, documented belief updating: “Brier scores are a measure of the quality of your probabilistic forecast... Whenever Brier scores are kept and feedback is given, decision makers get better.” Yet almost no investors track their own prediction quality systematically.
- Narratives and mental models—especially benign myths—can be powerful even if not strictly true. In closing, Mauboussin introduces the idea of “benign myths” from organizational theory—stories or frameworks that may not be empirically verifiable but motivate desirable behavior. He suggests that many investor beliefs (or business culture norms) fall into this category. For example, Jim Collins’s work may lack rigorous research backing, but it can still motivate effective behavior. Mauboussin’s epistemological humility is clear: sometimes a narrative can be wrong in fact, but useful in practice—and it’s the outcomes that matter.
Transcript
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣