Background
Michael Mauboussin is the Head of Global Financial Strategies at Credit Suisse. We cover moats and base rates, the active-passive debate, and the shift from public to private markets.
Date
May 16, 2017
Episode Number
37
Tags
Public Equities
Principles & Lessons:
- Markets are not perfectly efficient because information is costly—thus, inefficiency must persist to incentivize active participation. Mauboussin draws from Grossman and Stiglitz’s seminal idea: “Markets cannot be perfectly efficient because there's a cost to gathering information... there should be a requisite benefit in the form of inefficient markets.” This reframes efficiency not as a state, but a process sustained by incentives. The key implication is that while active management may underperform in aggregate, its existence is necessary to make prices informative. Thus, any claim that “everyone should go passive” ignores the structural role of active managers in enabling even passive efficiency.
- Relative skill matters more than absolute skill in competitive markets, and rising parity among participants compresses excess returns. Mauboussin emphasizes that most investment discussions misframe the problem: “The fact that we've got these fancy spreadsheets doesn't really matter because everyone has them.” The practical edge isn't having tools—it's having insight others lack. This means that even improving your skill doesn't guarantee better returns if others improve equally. It's a version of the Red Queen effect: “you have to run faster just to stay in place.” The more skilled the collective competition becomes, the more returns become a zero-sum redistribution of relative advantage.
- The decline in publicly listed companies shifts value capture to private markets, where informational edge is more feasible—but this amplifies access inequality. With the number of US public companies halving since 1996, Mauboussin warns that “more of the value is captured in private markets.” This has both structural and epistemic consequences. First, public investors can no longer capture the early-stage value creation that public markets once offered (e.g., Amazon IPO at $600 million vs. Facebook at $110 billion). Second, private markets enable alpha (due to less efficiency), but access is limited—creating a bifurcated system in which institutions and insiders disproportionately benefit from early-stage compounding.
- Behavioral gaps (buying high, selling low) matter more than fee differentials between active and passive strategies. Mauboussin cites data showing the average investor underperforms their fund by ~120 basis points per year due to timing errors—compared to a ~60 basis point fee difference between active and passive. He observes, “the behavioral gap is twice as important as the fee differential.” This challenges the prevailing focus on cost minimization and suggests a more important axis of improvement: designing investment systems that constrain harmful behavior, not just reduce expense ratios. It also supports the value of behavioral coaching in advisory contexts.
- Base rate reasoning provides an essential counterweight to narrative forecasting, offering measurable insight into regression to the mean. The base rate book Mauboussin discusses introduces structured historical distributions (e.g., sales growth, ROIC) to anchor expectations. For example, he notes that among all companies starting with $100B+ in revenue since 1950, none grew 15% annually for 10 years—yet analysts often project this for companies like Amazon. The inside view (detailed modeling) is prone to overconfidence; the outside view (base rates) corrects for this by quantifying how outcomes typically unfold. Regression to the mean is not just expected—it can be measured and applied through shrinkage factors.
- Industry context dominates firm-specific effects in high-return sectors, while firm-specific variation dominates in challenged sectors. In decomposing returns, Mauboussin finds that in successful industries, “industry matters most”; in struggling ones, “firm-specific effects dominate.” This asymmetry offers a strategic guide: analysts should anchor deeply in industry structure when evaluating strong performers, but should examine individual execution when analyzing distressed firms. This also complicates generalizations about “good management”—in high-return industries, many firms can succeed despite average leadership, while in poor-return industries, only a few firms escape decline due to exceptional idiosyncratic factors.
- Moats are best understood through sustained returns on capital, but must be contextualized through strategic trade-offs and industry dynamics. A moat is not just a metric—it is the strategic mechanism that allows value creation to persist. Mauboussin’s framework includes “industry maps,” “profit pool analysis,” “pricing power tests,” and “value chain positioning,” culminating in the core idea that strategy is defined by trade-offs. He emphasizes, “Until you get to the trade-off answer, you really haven't figured out the strategy.” This rejects vague narratives of “great companies” in favor of testable mechanisms for sustained competitive advantage—like whether a company sacrifices margin for scale, or vice versa.
- Quantitative rigor can complement narrative insight through shrinkage models that balance inside and outside views. Drawing from True Score Theory, Mauboussin presents a formula: Forecast = Base Rate + Shrinkage × (Observation – Base Rate). The shrinkage factor (0 ≤ C ≤ 1) quantifies the persistence of performance—higher when results are stable (e.g., consumer staples ROIC), lower when they’re noisy (e.g., S&P annual returns). This allows analysts to temper bottom-up forecasts with empirically calibrated reversion expectations. Crucially, the goal isn’t to suppress judgment, but to structure it. As he notes, “almost everyone knows regression happens. The question is at what rate?”
Transcript
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣
‣